首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
     检索      

政府绩效评估中的“控制权”分配与行动逻辑
引用本文:陈那波,陈永宏,谭茼丹.政府绩效评估中的“控制权”分配与行动逻辑[J].科研管理,2022,43(5):191-199.
作者姓名:陈那波  陈永宏  谭茼丹
作者单位:1.中山大学 政治与公共事务管理学院,广东 广州510275; 2.中山大学 附属口腔医院,广东 广州510055
基金项目:国家社会科学基金重大项目:“新时代县域社会治理能力建设研究”(18ZDA108,2018.11—2021.11);
摘    要:政府绩效管理的实质是以绩效合同为中心的设计、实施、验收和激励的整体流程。在开展绩效管理工作中,各方主体所持有的剩余控制权直接影响各方主体的行动逻辑,进而内化成各具特征的制度运行模式。为回答“如何开展绩效管理工作”以及“如何影响绩效管理工作结果”的问题,本研究以A市机关工委、B区组织部、C县地税局的绩效管理工作为例,借助“控制权”理论视角,基于“控制权”在绩效管理制度运行过程中的三个维度,即目标设定权、检查验收权、激励分配权,探讨权力配置与行动逻辑之间的影响关系,形成绩效管理“高度互动型”、“主导支配型”、“系统直控型”三种不同的制度运行模式。并且,权力配置会随着制度运行而发生转变,在影响各参与主体行动逻辑的同时,组织行为也在影响剩余控制权的再次组合分配。

关 键 词:绩效评估  控制权  权力配置  行动逻辑  
收稿时间:2021-07-08
修稿时间:2021-12-14

The "control right" distribution and action logic in government performance evaluation
Chen Nabo,Chen Yonghong,Tan Tongdan.The "control right" distribution and action logic in government performance evaluation[J].Science Research Management,2022,43(5):191-199.
Authors:Chen Nabo  Chen Yonghong  Tan Tongdan
Institution:1. School of Government, Sun Yat-sen University, Guangzhou 510275, Guangdong, China; 2. Hospital of Stomatology, Sun Yat-sen University, Guangzhou 510055, Guangdong, China;
Abstract:    Although government performance evaluation has undergone extensive scrutiny in academia, the existing literature largely hinges upon single-case studies, and considers the evaluation procedure a set of ‘complete’ contracting actions. Yet, there remains unclear about how power configurations within an organization have an impact on the process and outcomes of government performance evaluation. To take up this research question, this article draws on comparative case studies, and conducts a series of empirical investigations into the performance evaluation processes in three governmental organizations——The Municipal Work Committee of City A, The Organization Department of District B, and The Local Taxation Bureau of County C. Through a theoretical lens of control rights, this article develops a more sophisticated analytical framework, which consists of three dimensions, i.e., ‘target setting power’, ‘evaluation power’, and ‘incentive distribution power’, thereby unraveling different power configurations in these three cases. On this basis, we dissect how different types of power relations have led to varying attitudes and behavior of different stakeholders. Finally, we conclude three distinctive patterns of government performance evaluation, which include the ‘interactive’, ‘dominant’ and ‘direct-control’ modes.     This article attempts to make the following theoretical contributions: first, the comparative analysis across the aforementioned three cases substantiates the conceptual value of residual control rights in the research of government performance evaluation. Although these three cases are very much different in their functions, levels, goals, etc., they consistently show that performance evaluation is a dynamic and interactive process. In the first place, the planning of performance evaluation needs to be achieved through different forms of interaction and negotiation. Even after the evaluation plan is formulated, it is subject to any adjustment according to the changing contexts. There is also room for flexibility in the form of inspection and acceptance, as well as in the way of interpretation and announcement of results. The analytical framework of threefold dimensions i.e., ‘target setting power’, ‘evaluation power’, and ‘incentive distribution power’ helps us make classification among different cases, which provides the possibility for further abstraction and theorization of government performance evaluation.     Second, in the process of performance evaluation, the residual control rights held by the evaluator often determines the primary configuration of evaluation, therein lies different types of interrelations between evaluators and evaluatees. The less the residual control rights held by the evaluator, the higher scientificity and objectivity of the evaluation design are required (e.g., the evaluation project organized by the Municipal Work Committee of City A); on the contrary, the more emphasis is placed on the evaluation results and the corresponding incentive distribution, the focus on evaluation procedures and methods will tend to be reduced (e.g., the evaluation project undertaken by the Organization Department of B District). Nonetheless, excessive residual control rights held by the evaluator will lead to out-of-balance power relations, which will render the objectives of performance evaluation ineffective (e.g., the case of the Local Taxation Bureau of C County).     Third, these three residual control rights—i.e., ‘target setting power’, ‘evaluation power’, and ‘incentive distribution power’ are not at the same degree of importance, or does not work in the same way. More specifically, ‘incentive distribution power’ appears to be more decisive, which have an impact on the other two to a great extent. Besides, both the ‘target setting power’ and the ‘evaluation power’ are more likely to be transferred to the third parties through outsourcing. For example, the evaluator tends to assign part of the responsibility (such as the design of performance plans, and the inspection tasks, etc.) to a third institution. Outsourcing has become a common phenomenon in contemporary practices of government performance evaluation. However, the involvement of the third-party power may change the distribution of residual control rights, and thus would cause any uncertainty. Yet, viewed from the above three cases, the role of the third parties varies according to the difference in the allocation of residual control rights between the evaluator and the evaluatee. Under this circumstance, the third parties tend not to assume a decisive role.      Taken together, this article suggests that government performance evaluation is fundamentally an incomplete contracting process, which is embedded (and thus is mirrored) in the processes of target setting, implementation, measurement, and incentive provision. While Zhou and Lian′s seminal work (2012) employ the notion of ‘residual control rights’ to delves into the relatively static power relations among different levels of governments, this article endeavors to shed new light by indicating the variegated power configurations in government performance evaluation, which are formed by different stakeholders at multiple levels and positions. In these processes, residual control rights held by all parties affect the logic of their actions directly, which in turn make them internalized into different modes of government performance evaluation. 
Keywords:performance evaluation  control right  power allocation  action logic  
点击此处可从《科研管理》浏览原始摘要信息
点击此处可从《科研管理》下载免费的PDF全文
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号